1 Decentralisation in Cameroon and the Anglophones’ Struggle for Autonomy Emmanuel Makia Epongo A thesis submitted to the Faculty of Commerce, Law and Management, University of the Witwatersrand, in fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy. Supervisor: Professor Anthoni Van Nieuwkerk Co-supervisor: Dr. John Khumalo May 18, 2023 2 Abstract In Cameroon, decentralisation was introduced in 1996 to promote development, democracy and good governance at the local level. However, decentralisation exacerbated conflicts between the Anglophone minority and the Francophone-majority government, resulting in a civil war in 2017. Therefore, this research explores how the implementation of decentralisation in the two Anglophone regions exacerbated conflicts between the Anglophone minority and the Francophone-majority government. Despite the growing literature on decentralisation and conflicts, very little research has been conducted on conflicts arising from former independent colonial territories that reunited under a federal system and later evolved to a decentralised unitary system, a shortcoming addressed by this research. This study used qualitative methodology and a case study design. The research was conducted at the Kumba and Bamenda city councils in the Southwest and Northwest regions, respectively. Participants were selected through purposive and snowball sampling techniques for semi-structured interviews. Data from interviews, observation and archival documents were merged and analysed through thematic analysis. The findings suggest that decentralisation in the Anglophone regions is more of deconcentration than devolution. Understanding how decentralisation increased intrastate conflict between the Anglophone minority and the Francophone-majority government could have a broader significance for researchers, governments and policymakers seeking to mitigate conflicts, particularly in Africa, with diverse societies prone to intrastate conflicts. Keywords: decentralisation, intrastate conflicts, mitigate conflicts, eroded autonomy, divided societies. 3 DECLARATION I declare that this thesis is my own, unaided work. It is submitted in partial fulfilment of the requirements of the degree of Doctor of Philosophy at the University of the Witwatersrand, Johannesburg. It has not been submitted before for any degree or examination in any other University. ----------------------------------------- Emmanuel Makia Epongo May 18, 2023 4 DEDICATION This thesis is dedicated to my beloved parents of blessed memory, Papa Epongo Paul Eyambe and Mama Esther Tua Epongo, who encouraged me to get a good education. 5 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I am grateful to God for helping me to complete this thesis. Twenty-eight years ago, I left Cameroon by road to study law at the University of Witwatersrand, but I got stranded in the Democratic Republic of Congo. That experience changed my life and purpose. I thought I had failed, but God had a different plan. In 2013, my wife was transferred to the U.S. Consulate in Johannesburg, South Africa. While in Johannesburg, I applied to the Law School at Wits, but the Director sent my application to the Wits School of Governance, where I was accepted. I thank my first supervisor, Dr. Manamela Matshabaphala, for his guidance before transferring to Wits Business School. I am grateful to the Director of the WSG for assigning me new supervisors. I sincerely thank Professor Anthoni Van Nieukerk for agreeing to supervise my thesis and the Co-supervisor Dr. John Khumalo. Without their assistance, this research would not have been possible. I am eternally grateful to my wife for accepting the transfer to South Africa and for her moral and financial support. I am also grateful to my son, who did not take offence whenever I could not attend some of his social activities and basketball games because I had to work on my paper. I am grateful to the staff at the WSG secretariat and the faculty for their assistance throughout my study. I am also thankful to my late parents, Pa Epongo and Mama Esther, for encouraging me to continue my education. Finally, I am grateful to all the participants who participated in my research, whose names cannot be mentioned here because of ethical considerations. Without you all, I would not have completed this research. 6 LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS AAC1 All Anglophone Conference 1 AAC2 All Anglophone Conference 2 AD Administrative Decentralisation CFA African financial community CDF Common Decentralisation Fund CPDM Cameroon People’s Democratic Movement DO Divisional officer ECG East Cameroon Government ELECAM Elections Cameroon FC French Cameroun FEICOM Special council support fund FD Fiscal Decentralisation GD Government Delegate IDPs Internally Displaced Persons NA Native Authority NDF National Decentralisation Fund PD Political Decentralisation 7 PIB Public Investment Budget SDF Social Democratic Front SDO Senior Divisional Officer SC Southern Cameroons SCNC Southern Cameroons National Council TB Tender Board UN United Nations WCG West Cameroon Government 8 TABLE OF CONTENTS Abstract 2 DECLARATION 3 DEDICATION 4 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS 5 LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS 6 TABLE OF CONTENTS 8 CHAPTER ONE 12 1.1 Introduction 12 1.2 Background to the Study 16 1.3 Statement of the Problem 20 1.4 Purpose Statement 22 1.5 Research Questions. 24 1.6 Scope of the Study 25 1.7 Significance of the Study 26 1.8 Definition of terms 31 1.8.1 Types of Decentralisation 32 1.8.1.2 Political Decentralisation 32 1.8.1.3 Fiscal Decentralisation 33 1.8.1.4 Administrative Decentralisation 34 1.8.1.5 Economic or Market Decentralisation 35 1.8.2 Forms of Decentralisation 36 1.8.2.1 Deconcentration 36 1.8.2.2 Delegation 37 1.8.2.3 Devolution 38 1.8.3 Autonomy 39 1.8.4 Conclusion 40 CHAPTER TWO 41 2.1. Introduction 41 2.2 Decentralisation can either reduce or increase conflicts. 42 2.3. Decentralisation has the potential to reduce conflicts. 47 2.4. Decentralisation can exacerbate conflicts 54 2.5. Conclusion 59 2.6. The Theoretical Framework 60 2.6.1 Decentralisation and Conflict Mitigation: Theoretical Considerations 63 2.6.2 The erosion of Anglophones’ autonomy exacerbated conflicts 71 9 2.6.2.1 Historical Context 71 2.6.2.2 Decentralisation further eroded the autonomy of Anglophones 79 2.6.2.3 Conclusion 87 CHAPTER THREE 88 3.1 Introduction 88 3.2 Qualitative Research Methodology 88 3.3 Case Study Design 96 3.4 Method of Data Collection 103 3.4.1 Interviews 104 3.4.1.1 Sequencing of the Interviews 108 3.4.1.2 Data 108 3.4.1.3 Sampling Strategy 109 3.4.1.4 Author positionality 110 3.4.1.5 Participants 112 3.4.1.6 Procedure 114 3.4.1.7 Time Horizon 116 3.5.1 Documentation 117 3.5.2 Participant Observation 119 3.5 Ethical Considerations 121 3.6 Method of Data Analysis 126 3.6.1 Thematic Analysis 126 3.6.2 Applying the Six-step Process by Braun and Clarke 135 3.6.2.1 Step 1: Familiarising with the data set 135 3.6.2.2 Step 2: Generating initial codes from all the data. 135 3.6.2.3 Step 3: Searching for themes. 177 3.6.2.4 Step 4: Reviewing themes. 180 3.6.2.5 Step 5: Defining and naming themes: 183 3.7.3 Conclusion 184 CHAPTER FOUR 185 4.1 Introduction 185 4. 2 Methodology 185 4. 3 Producing the report 188 4.3.1 Political Decentralisation 189 4.3.1.1 Democratic Elections 189 4.3.1.2 Citizen Representation 192 4.3.1.3 Citizen Participation 194 4.3.2 Fiscal Decentralisation 198 4.3.2.1 Revenue Autonomy 198 10 4.3.2.2 Expenditure Autonomy 202 4.3.3 Administrative Decentralisation 205 4.3.3.1 Accountability 206 4.3.3.2 Decision-making Authority 211 4.3.3.3 Local Autonomy 213 4.3.4 Conflict 221 4.3.5 Local Conflicts 221 4.3.5.1 Ambiguous Laws 222 4.3.5.2 Resource Allocation 223 4.3.5.3 Power Struggle 225 4.3.6 National Conflict 228 4.3.6.1 Eroded Autonomy 228 4.3.6.2 Lack of Political Will 234 4.3.6.3 Perception of Decentralisation 239 4.3.6.4 Conclusion 245 CHAPTER FIVE 246 5.1 Introduction 246 5.1.1 Decentralisation is more of deconcentration than devolution. 247 5.1.2 Decentralisation further eroded the autonomy of Anglophones 258 5.1.3 Decentralisation marginalised, discriminated and assimilated Anglophones. 263 5.1.4 Decentralisation increased conflicts. 267 5.1.5 Conclusion 272 CHAPTER SIX 273 6.1 Introduction 273 6.2 Discussion 273 6.2.1 Summary of the four key findings 274 6.2.2 Interpretation and implications of the results 276 6.2.2.1 Decentralisation is more of deconcentration than devolution 276 6.2.2.2 Decentralisation further eroded the autonomy of Anglophones 284 6.2.2.3 Decentralisation marginalised, discriminated and assimilated Anglophones 293 6.2.2.4 Decentralisation increased conflicts 300 6.2.2.5 Limitations of the study 309 6.2.2.6 Suggestions for future research in the field 311 6.2.2.7 Recommendations for policy intervention 313 6.2.2.8 Conclusion 321 CHAPTER SEVEN 323 7.1 Introduction 323 7.2 Summary of the key findings 323 11 7.3 How the research aims and objectives were fulfilled 325 7.4 Contribution of this study to theory and practice 333 7.5 Conclusion 341 REFERENCES 342 Appendix A: Informed Consent Form 364 Appendix B: Participant Information Sheet 367 Appendix C: Interview questions 369 Appendix D: Proposed 1960 Federal Constitution 373 Appendix E: Ethics Clearance Certificate & Wits Permission Letter 374 Appendix F: Authorisation Letter to do research in Bamenda. 375 Appendix G: Authorisation Letter to do research in Kumba 377 12 CHAPTER ONE INTRODUCTION AND BACKGROUND OF THE STUDY 1.1 Introduction With the rise of intrastate conflicts worldwide, governments have adopted decentralisation as a popular strategy for mitigating conflicts in divided societies (Brancati, 2006; Fujikawa, 2021). This research is about the implementation of decentralisation in the two Anglophone regions of the Southwest and Northwest and their struggle for autonomy from the central government. The modern state of Cameroon was founded when British Southern Cameroons (hereinafter called Anglophones) joined French Cameroun (hereinafter called Francophones) as an autonomous territory in 1961 under a federal system. In 1996, Cameroon became a decentralised unitary state to promote development, democracy, and good governance at the local level. However, the implementation of decentralisation in the two Anglophone regions intensified intrastate conflicts, leading to the ongoing civil war in the Anglophone regions between Anglophone armed groups and the central government (Nwati, 2021; Nkongho, 2018). Therefore, this research explored how decentralisation exacerbated intrastate conflicts in Cameroon. This paper examined the design of decentralisation and the degree of autonomy devolved to the Anglophone regions by studying the Kumba and Bamenda city councils in the Southwest and Northwest regions, respectively. The findings suggest that the form of decentralisation implemented in the Anglophone regions is more of deconcentration than devolution because decentralisation has failed to transfer sufficient powers and resources to the Anglophones to manage their local affairs with limited 13 interference from the central government. Instead of decentralisation restoring the lost autonomy of Anglophones, it further eroded their autonomy, thus exacerbating intrastate conflicts. Autonomy is essential in conflict mitigation, especially for minority groups like the Anglophones with different preferences and spatially concentrated in a specific area and have different preferences (Fujikawa, 2021; Aime, 2020; Tranchant, 2007). Decentralisation has the potential to reduce conflicts by empowering minority groups with independent decision-making powers to design and implement policies according to their preferences (Seabright, 1996; Hechter, 2000, Gurr, 2000, Brancati, 2006; Tranchant, 2007; 2016; Grasa & Camps, 2009; Burgess, 2011; Durante, 2017, Fukijawa, 2021). However, decentralisation could also intensify conflicts by eroding the autonomy of minority groups (Merera, 2007; Woodward, 2007; Sambanis & Milanovic, 2009; Mbuagbo & Fru, 2011; Goodfellow & Lindermann, 2013; Marinzel, 2014) and by reinforcing ethnic and regional identities (Brancati, 2006; Eaton, 2006; Beland & Lecours, 2005; 2007; Colomb, Bakke & Tomaney, 2014). Therefore, it is contended that decentralisation increases conflicts when the central government erodes the autonomy of a minority group within a unitary state that previously enjoyed some form of autonomy before joining the host state. Adopting a theoretical framework which explains how decentralisation exacerbates intrastate conflicts in a decentralised unitary state could have a broader significance for governments and policymakers seeking to mitigate conflicts, particularly in Africa, with diverse societies prone to internal conflicts (Keller, 2007; Burgess, 2011). This study is organised into seven chapters. Chapter one begins with the introduction and is followed by the background to the study, problem statement, purpose 14 of the study, research questions, scope of the study, significance of the research and definition of the terms. This chapter provides a general understanding of the concept of decentralisation and how governments are increasingly using decentralisation as an effective mechanism for managing intrastate conflicts. In this chapter, the researcher argues that decentralisation increases conflicts when the central government continues to erode the autonomy of a minority group that previously enjoyed some form of autonomy before joining the host state (Merera, 2007; Marinzel, 2014). Chapter two focuses on the literature review, assessing the ongoing debate and the conflicting themes, and the theory of decentralisation that guided this study. Decentralisation has the potential to either increase or reduce conflicts depending on the circumstance (Brancati, 2006). The researcher argues that the decentralisation laws and their implementation failed to ease conflicts owing to their weak design and poor implementation. Chapter three outlines the methods section, including qualitative methodology, case study design, data collection method and data analysis and the justification for their selection. The researcher chose the qualitative methodology because this research is grounded in the interpretive paradigm, and researchers in the interpretive tradition seek to understand a phenomenon from the perspectives and experiences of participants. Chapter four is the write-up report of the thematic analysis. The chapter describes the process that was followed to analyse the data and produce the report. In producing the report, the researcher used the six-step process developed by Braun and Clarke (2006). Chapter five presents the findings/results of the study. The key finding of this study is that the form of decentralisation implemented in the two Anglophone regions is more of deconcentration than devolution because the weak design and poor implementation of decentralisation 15 failed to transfer real power to the Anglophone regions. Chapter six deals with the discussion and recommendations. In the discussions, the findings are presented in the form of themes directly related to the research questions. The pattern of results is consistent with past studies on decentralisation in the literature. The chapter also discusses the study’s limitations, provides suggestions for future research in the field and offers recommendations for policy intervention to mitigate the ongoing conflict. Chapter seven is the conclusion of the study. The chapter summarises the key research findings related to the research aim and questions and how the research helps address the gap in the study. This chapter also discusses the value and contribution of this research to the field of knowledge both in terms of theory and practice, The study ends with references and appendices sections. 16 1.2 Background to the Study Since the end of the Second World War, intrastate conflicts have become the most common type of conflict rather than wars between nations (Bakke, 2008; Sambanis & Milanovic, 2009). To prevent these types of conflicts, governments have turned to decentralisation as one of the tools for managing intrastate conflicts while preserving the territorial integrity of the actual state (Schrottshammer, 2006; Bakke, 2008; Keil & Anderson, 2018). Decentralisation is defined as the transfer of responsibility for planning, management, and the raising and allocation of resources from the central government and its agencies to field units of government agencies, subordinate units or levels of government, semi-autonomous public authorities or corporations, area-wide, regional or functional authorities, or non-governmental private or voluntary organisations (Rondinelli, Nellis & Cheema, 1983:13). This definition is relevant to this study because it shows intergovernmental fiscal relations and the relationships between the government and outside organisations, working together to make the government more efficient in providing public goods and services (Tiebouts, 1956; Oates, 1972). This concept of governance does not view decision-making as the exclusive domain of the central government but also as the right of citizens and the private sector to shape public policy (Cheema & Rondinelli, 2007). The assumption is that decentralisation would reduce intrastate conflict by empowering regional and local governments or minority groups to design and implement public policies according to their preferences (Tranchant, 2007; Brancati, 2006; Hechter, 2000; Gurr, 2000). Decentralisation has been used in developed and developing nations to mitigate intrastate conflicts. Several scholars (Brancati, 2006; Tranchant, 2007; Bakke, 2008) 17 suggest that political decentralisation has been successful in reducing ethnic conflicts and secession in developed countries like Belgium, Spain, Canada, Switzerland, United Kingdom, as well as in developing countries like Brazil, Nigeria, India, and Bosnia-Herzegovina. African countries have also implemented decentralisation to promote stability, democracy, and development (USAID, 2010). However, Burges (2011) suggests that decentralisation has had a limited impact on containing intrastate conflicts, especially in Central Africa, the most undemocratic and unstable region, comprising mostly French countries, including Cameroon. Ndegwa (2002:16) describes the overall pace of decentralisation in Africa as “moderate”, with the least decentralisation occurring in Francophone countries. In 1996, Cameroon adopted decentralisation, but it exacerbated conflicts, leading to a civil war in 2017 between Anglophone armed groups and the central government. Numerous studies have been conducted on decentralisation and ethnic or regional conflicts (Brancati, 2006; Bakke, 2008; Sambanis & Milanovic, 2009). These studies have found that decentralisation reduces conflicts by granting ethnic or regional groups autonomy (Lake & Rothchild, 1996; Tranchant, 2007, 2016; Durante, 2017; Fujikawa, 2021), sharing political power (Burgess, 2011; Grasa & Camps, 2009; Noris, 2008) and accommodating ethnic diversity (Miodownik & Cartrite, 2009; Yusoff, Sarjoon & Hassan, 2016). However, decentralisation increases conflicts by undermining the autonomy of local governments and ethnic or regional groups (Mbuagbo & Fru, 2011; Tambulasi, 2009; Merera, 2007; Goodfellow & Lindemann, 2013) and by empowering regional groups with resources to demand greater autonomy or secession (Brancati, 2006; Eaton, 2006; Beland & Lecours, 2005, 2007; Colomb et al., 2014). These studies have 18 focused on conflicts between governments and ethnic or regional groups seeking greater autonomy or independence. However, very little research has been conducted to understand the relationship between decentralisation and conflicts between former independent United Nations Trust Territories that reunited under a federal system but later evolved into a unitary state, especially when their colonial histories, socio-cultural and political characteristics were different. The sparse research has created room for further research. Therefore, this study explored how decentralisation intensified conflicts between the Anglophone minority and the Francophone-majority government. If the ongoing conflict is unchecked, as Dahrendorf (1958) claims, it could intensify and lead to more deaths. Several studies (Tiryakian, 1998; Premdas, 2000; Marinzel; 2014) suggest that groups try to secede when governments fail to rectify conditions of discontent. Hence, this research aimed to understand how decentralisation exacerbated intrastate conflicts in Cameroon. Before joining French Cameroon in 1961, the Anglophone territory was an autonomous region and under the federal system, Anglophones continued to enjoy some degree of autonomy. However, under decentralisation, Anglophone regions do not have any exclusive jurisdiction. Therefore, this research argues that decentralisation intensified intrastate conflicts by failing to restore the lost autonomy of Anglophones and further eroding their autonomy due to its poor design and implementation. For example, Eyoh (1998) and Anyefru (2011) claim that the Francophone-dominated government has used state laws to dismantle the autonomy and cultural heritage of the Anglophones. Research by Aime (2020) suggests that the Constitutional and legal framework of decentralisation under the 1996 19 Constitution, among other things, failed to address the perception of Anglophone marginalisation adequately. Mbuagbo and Fru (2011), based on the study of the 2004 Law implementing decentralisation in Cameroon, found that the appointment of government officials over regional and local authorities undermined the authority of elected mayors and councillors, thus resulting in conflicts. Similarly, Cheka (2007) claims that the appointment of government delegates in Cameroon to supervise regional and local authorities subverted the democratic principles of electoral accountability. According to the World Bank (2011:4), “Cameroon lacks an effective and an operational plan for decentralisation. Indeed, line ministries appear to regard decentralisation as a threat to the control over resources and their influence”. Ndiva (2011:524) suggests that Cameroon’s form of decentralisation “resembles more a false version of devolution than the real one”. According to Fombad and Steytler (2019), the design of decentralisation in the form of deconcentration in Cameroon is a disguise for the central government to maintain power and control over regional and local authorities. Similar studies outside Cameroon (Tambulasi, 2009; Marinzel, 2014; Goodfellow & Lindermanne, 2013; Merera, 2007; Woodward, 2007; Sambanis & Milanovic, 2009) also suggest that decentralisation exacerbates conflicts by eroding the autonomy of minority groups, especially those which have previously enjoyed some degree of independence before joining the host state. Given the above discussion, this study suggests that the failure of decentralisation to restore the autonomy of Anglophones, coupled with a weak design and poor implementation, intensified intrastate conflicts, resulting in a civil war in 2017. Therefore, this research explored how decentralisation exacerbated conflicts between the 20 Anglophone minority and the Francophone-majority government and proposed recommendations that could help mitigate the ongoing conflict. 1.3 Statement of the Problem The key problem addressed in this research is that the implementation of decentralisation in Cameroon in 1996 has exacerbated intrastate conflicts between the Anglophone minority and the Francophone-majority government, which led to a civil war in 2017. According to Ngoh (2011), Anglophones have been complaining about the erosion of their autonomy since independence. Therefore, during the constitutional debates leading up to the 1996 decentralised unitary Constitution, Anglophone leaders called for the government to return to federalism so that each territory would regain its autonomy (Munzu, 2016). Also, in 2015, Anglophone Common Law lawyers called for the government to return to a federal system. After the government rejected their requests, the lawyers organised a peaceful protest, but some of their leaders were arrested and tried in court for treason (Nkongho, 2018). That led some Anglophones to create self-defence groups to continue their struggle. On December 30, 2017, President Paul Biya declared war on the Anglophone armed groups (Nwati, 2021). While most conflicts in the literature have been between central governments and ethnic or regional groups seeking greater autonomy or independence (Bakke, 2008; Sambanis & Milanovic, 2009), very few studies have examined decentralisation and conflicts between former independent United Nations trust territories that reunited under a federal system but later evolved to a unitary state. Therefore, this study explored how 21 decentralisation exacerbated conflicts between the Anglophone minority and the Francophone-majority government. Previous studies on decentralisation intensifying conflicts have focused on minority’s grievances against their central governments (Durante, 2017; Hechter, 2000; Gurr, 2000; Goodfellow & Lindemann, 2013; Merera, 2007; Mbuagbo & Fru, 2011) and decentralisation reinforcing ethnic and regional identities (Roeder 1991; Bunce, 1999; Brancati, 2006; Eaton 2006; Beland & Lecours, 2005; 2007; Colomb et al., 2014). However, these studies have not examined how the historical context influences the design of decentralisation to erode the autonomy of minorities with different colonial histories within a unitary state, thus leading to conflicts. Insufficient research has created the opportunity for further study. The motivation for this research came from the desire to understand why decentralisation would mitigate intrastate conflicts in other countries but not in Cameroon. Therefore, this study explored how decentralisation intensified intrastate conflicts in Cameroon. The ongoing conflict is not only destroying human lives and property, forcing thousands of Anglophones to flee to Nigeria as refugees and displacing thousands of Anglophones from their homes, slowing down the economy and preventing children from attending schools regularly, but it is also encouraging kidnappings, rapping, looting, burning of villages, arms trafficking, and threatening the territorial integrity of the nation and regional peace (Nkongho, 2018; Nwati, 2021). After six years of fighting, over 6,000 people have died in the Anglophone regions, thousand displaced, about 600,000 children deprived of education and over 2.2 million people need humanitarian support (International Crisis Group, 2023, March 31). Therefore, understanding how decentralisation increased conflict between the Anglophone minority and the 22 Francophone-majority government could contribute new knowledge to conflict resolution and offer new insights to policymakers in Cameroon on how to contain the ongoing conflict and restore peace in the nation. To do this, the researcher conducted qualitative research with a case study design. Data collected was analysed through thematic analysis to propose policy interventions. 1.4 Purpose Statement The purpose of this qualitative case study was to explore how the implementation of decentralisation in the Kumba city council in the Southwest and Bamenda city council in the Northwest regions of the two Anglophone regions exacerbated conflicts between the Anglophone minority and the Francophone-majority government of Cameroon since it was instituted in 1996. The following five objectives aim to fulfil the purpose of this study: 1. To explore how the implementation of decentralisation exacerbated conflicts between the Anglophone minority and the Francophone-majority government. Before reunification, Anglophones had a government, legislature, constitution, and judiciary and exercised control over their legal system, economy, education, politics and language. However, Anglophones have no exclusive jurisdiction on any subject matter under decentralisation. 2. To understand the meaning of decentralisation and how it is implemented in the Anglophone regions. According to section 2 (1) of the 2004 law, decentralisation 23 shall consist of devolution by the state of special powers and resources to regional and local authorities. 3. To understand the lived experiences of Anglophones under the decentralisation program. Several scholars claim that Anglophones have been marginalised, discriminated and even annexed by Francophones (Konings & Nyamnjoh, 1997; Eyoh, 1998; Anyangwe, 2009; Gorji-Dinka, 1985; Fanso, 2009; Kah, 2010; Ngoh, 2011), while others think that Anglophones have been treated as second class citizens and slaves (Anyangwe, 2009; Ambe,2021). Some Francophone elites have described Anglophones as “enemies in the house” and have called them “Biafrans”, meaning foreigners from the Igbo region of Nigeria. They have also described Anglophones as “dogs”, “roaches which need to be exterminated”, “terrorists” about the armed groups and “two cubes of sugar in a basin” (Mukong, 1998:22; Ngamfon, 2020:1484) 4. To understand how Anglophones perceived the decentralisation program. Anglophones perceived the program as a sham because the poor design and implementation further eroded the autonomy of Anglophones. According to Eyoh (1998) and Anyefru (2011), the Francophone-dominated government uses state laws to dismantle the autonomy and cultural heritage of the Anglophones. Anglophones also viewed the concentration of power with the central government as a political ploy by the Francophones to maintain control over Anglophones (Anyangwe, 2009; Gorji-Dinka, 1985; Fanso, 2013). 5. To identify the reasons motivating Anglophones to continue their struggle for autonomy. Anglophones were motivated to continue their struggle because of a poorly 24 designed decentralisation that resulted in the marginalisation, discrimination and assimilation of Anglophones (Konings & Nyamnjoh, 1997; Eyoh, 1998; Mukong, 1998, Anyangwe, 2009; Gorji-Dinka, 1985; Fanso, 2009, Ngamfon, 2020; Ambe, 2012) 1.5 Research Questions. The research questions are derived from the five objectives in the purpose statement. Therefore, the following questions are set as guidelines to fulfil the purpose of this research. The main research question is 1. How did decentralisation exacerbate conflict between the Anglophone minority and the Francophone-majority government? The sub-questions are 2. What is the meaning of decentralisation, and how is it implemented in the Anglophone regions? 3. What are the experiences of Anglophones under the decentralisation program? 4. How do Anglophones perceive the decentralisation program? 5. What reasons motivate Anglophones to continue their struggle for autonomy? 25 1.6 Scope of the Study The purpose of this research was to explore how the implementation of decentralisation in the two Anglophone regions of the Southwest and Northwest exacerbated conflict between the Anglophone minority and the majority Francophone-led government. The specific subject investigated was the devolution of power by the state to the local government in the two Anglophone regions. The goal was to understand how the implementation of decentralisation further eroded the autonomy of Anglophones, thus leading to intrastate conflicts. The study was conducted only in the two Anglophone regions, namely, at the Kumba city council in the Southwest region and the Bamenda city council in the Northwest region. Each city council has three sub-divisional councils within the city council area. The research was conducted in all six sub-divisional councils, including the two city councils. This research began in 2014 and will end in 2023. The researcher travelled to Cameroon in 2016 to conduct interviews in Kumba and Bamenda from January to March 2016. The study participants were all Anglophones who lived and worked in the two Anglophone regions. While some were selected for their knowledge and experience of the decentralisation program, others were chosen for their political activism. Using purposive and snowball sampling strategies, 49 key informants participated in the study (Merriam, 2002; Neuman, 2011; Wahyuni, 2012). The participants included representatives of the senior divisional officers (SDO) and government delegates (GD), mayors or their representatives, municipal treasurers, council secretary generals, councillors, activists, community leaders and academics. This study used qualitative methodology with a case study design. Data were obtained from 26 interviews, observation, and archival documents. The data were merged and analysed through thematic analysis (Baxter & Jack, 2008; Braun & Clarke, 2006). This study was not about the failures and successes of decentralisation in Cameroon; instead, it was about the implementation of decentralisation and the Anglophones’ struggle for autonomy. Second, this research focused only on decentralisation even though there are other institutional designs for mitigating intrastate conflicts, such as federalism (Wolff, 2011), veto rights for minorities, proportional representation (Keil & Anderson, 2018) and consociational or other power-sharing arrangements (Lijphart, 2004; Norris, 2008; Burgess, 2011). 1.7 Significance of the Study The findings of this research could add new knowledge to the field of decentralisation and conflict mitigation while also benefiting specific groups like the Anglophones, the government of Cameroon, policymakers, researchers, international organisations and countries interested in conflict mitigation in Africa. In the literature, decentralisation is perceived as an effective mechanism for conflict mitigation in divided societies, but in practice, decentralisation is more successful in reducing conflicts in some countries than in others (Brancati, 2006). Several scholars suggest that decentralisation reduces conflict when minority groups are empowered to meet their needs (Gurr, 2000; Grasa & Camps, 2009; Tranchant, 2007; Keil & Anderson, 2018). On the other hand, others are convinced that decentralisation intensifies conflicts when the central government erodes the autonomy of minority groups (Goodfellow & Lindemann, 2013; 27 Merera, 2007; Mbuagbo & Fru, 2011) and reinforces ethnic and regional identities (Brancati, 2006; Eaton, 2006; Beland & Lecours, 2005, 2007; Colomb et al., 2014). However, others maintain that decentralisation has the potential to either decrease or intensify conflicts depending on the particular circumstance (Brancati, 2006; Bakke, 2008; Siegle & O’Mahony, 2006). While most of the research has focused on the relationship between decentralisation and ethnic or regional conflicts (Brancati, 2006; Bakke, 2008; Sambanis & Milanovic, 2009), there has been little research on decentralisation and intrastate conflicts between former independent United Nations Trust Territories that reunited under a federal system but later evolved to a unitary state, a shortcoming addressed by this research. According to Schou and Haug (2005), studies on how decentralisation is used to manage conflicts and diversity in multiethnic states that have evolved into unitary states are lacking in the literature. In 1996, Cameroon adopted decentralisation to promote development, democracy and good governance at the local level. However, decentralisation exacerbated intrastate conflicts, resulting in a civil war in 2017. Therefore, this research explored how decentralisation exacerbated conflicts between the Anglophone minority and the Francophone-majority government. Before joining French Cameroon in 1961, the Anglophone territory was an autonomous region and under the federal system, Anglophones continued to enjoy some degree of autonomy. This research argued that decentralisation increased intrastate conflicts between the Anglophone minority and the Francophone-majority government because it failed to restore the autonomy rights of Anglophones. Second, the weak design and poor implementation further eroded the autonomy of Anglophones, thus leading to a civil war in 2017. 28 Therefore, the findings of this study could add new knowledge to the field of conflict mitigation, which previous studies had not adequately addressed, thus narrowing the gap in the literature. The findings of this study could also benefit researchers and academics. In a world where intrastate conflicts are on the rise, the responsibility of researchers and scholars, who are trying to resolve intrastate conflicts, has become more relevant (Bakke, 2008; Sambanis & Milanovic, 2009). Scholars and practitioners of decentralisation hope to find new ways or insights to mitigate conflicts or prevent wars resulting from intrastate conflicts that threaten international peace. Therefore, the findings of this study could inspire other scholars to build on this study and improve on the findings by overcoming some of the limitations in the study. There is also a lack of consensus among scholars and practitioners regarding the effectiveness of decentralisation in mitigating conflicts in divided societies. Therefore, this research findings highlighting the importance of the historical context in designing and implementing decentralisation could advance the debate. The ongoing conflict threatens the territorial integrity of the state of Cameroon as many activists and separatist groups are now demanding the independence of their territory, which they now call “Ambazonia” (Anyangew; 2017; Ngamfon, 2020; Nwati, 2021). Therefore, the findings of this study could help Cameroon's government understand why Anglophones continue their struggle for autonomy and respond positively. According to Lustick et al. (2004), when governments respond positively to the demands of disgruntled minorities, decentralisation can prevent secession while preserving the state’s territorial integrity. On the other hand, groups try to secede when 29 governments fail to rectify conditions of discontent and disregard mechanisms for regulating social conflicts (Dahrendorf, 1958; Tiryakian, 1998; Marinzel, 2014 ). Therefore, understanding Anglophones' grievances and empowering them to define their local affairs could encourage them to abandon their quest for independence, thus preserving the state’s territorial integrity. Mitigating the ongoing conflict could also help deepen democracy and good governance in the Anglophone regions where the conflict continues. According to Schou and Haug (2005), conflicts weaken local governance institutions and civil society because resources are diverted from these institutions to war efforts and areas of heavy fighting. Additionally, the ongoing conflict is affecting the economy of Cameroon; therefore, resolving this conflict is critical. According to the International Crisis Group (ICG, 2019, September 26), the Cameroon Development Corporation (CDC) and PAMOL, two of the country's biggest agricultural companies, have lost up to 80 per cent of their capacity. Also, pressure is being put on the Cameroon military as they are fighting incursions and cross-border raids and attacks in the Far North Region from Boko Haram, a radical jihadist group from Northern Nigeria. Furthermore, there are thousands of refugees in Cameroon from the Central African Republic (CAR) due to the conflict in CAR in 2012. Cameroon also shares a common border with Nigeria, which also has domestic conflicts, including the widespread activities of Boko Haram. The terrorist group has carried out attacks in the neighbouring countries of Cameroon, Chad and Niger. Due to the conflicts, refugees flee from Nigeria to Cameroon (Nwati, 2021). The Democratic Republic of Congo also experiences conflicts, forcing refugees to move to neighbouring countries, 30 including Cameroon (Kuku, 2019; Institute for Peace & Security Studies, 2020). Therefore, the findings of this study could also help promote regional peace and stability. Anglophones could also benefit from this study if the government of Cameroon redesigns the decentralisation program to grant them their autonomy. First, ending the conflict would stop the killing of innocent civilians, restore peace in the regions and encourage IDPs and refugees to return to their homes. It will also enable all schools to reopen so students can continue their education and allow businesses and companies that closed down to return to the regions. Second, Anglophones and Francophones have different preferences in terms of language, law, education, political values, culture and social norms because of their colonial history (Brain & Eyongetah, 1974). Therefore, granting them autonomy will enable Anglophones to design and implement policies to produce group-specific public goods and services (Tiebout, 1956; Oates, 1972; Sambanis & Milanovic, 2009). Finally, more wars are fought worldwide from intrastate conflicts than interstate conflicts (Brancati, 2006; Bakke, 2008; Keil & Anderson, 2018). Therefore, the findings of this research could help international organisations and donor countries prevent or resolve conflicts, thus promoting international peace and stability in conflict-prone nations. Several studies (Bardhan, 2002, Shar & Thompson, 2004; Grasa & Camps, 2009) suggest that the World Bank has embraced decentralisation as a major governance reform program. According to Van de Walle (2003:6), the World Bank promotes national decentralisation policies, arguing that low-income countries should focus on “core public goods and services” and transfer other responsibilities to local governments, the private sector and voluntary organisations to meet the needs of their people. Cheema and 31 Rondinelli (2007) claim that the International Monetary Fund, World Bank and other international development organisations support decentralisation to strengthen democracy and promote good governance worldwide. Jan (2014) claims that the World Bank and IMF have also given financial and institutional support to decentralisation reforms throughout Africa. Researchers Keil and Anderson (2018) also claim that the UN Department for Political Affairs has a unit that supports decentralisation programs. Therefore, the findings of this study could provide new insights to local, regional and international organisations involved in conflict mitigation in divided societies. 1.8 Definition of terms Decentralisation is defined as the transfer of responsibility for planning, management, and the raising and allocation of resources from the central government and its agencies to field units of government agencies, subordinate units or levels of government, semi-autonomous public authorities or corporations, area-wide, regional or functional authorities, or non-governmental private or voluntary organisations (Rondinelli, Nellis & Cheema, 1983:13). This definition is appropriate for this study for three reasons. First, it establishes an intergovernmental relationship within the government and a relationship between the government and private organisations. This definition does not only view decision-making as the exclusive domain of the central government but also as the right of citizens and the private sector to shape public policy (Cheema & Rondinelli, 2007). Second, this definition provides an institutional framework for citizen participation in local government through free and fair elections (Besley & Smart, 2007; Crook & Manor, 2000). Third, this definition promotes market-based ideas of decentralisation. Through these ideas, the central government strengthens the private sector, deregulates, and 32 privatises those activities that the private sector and civil society organisations could carry out more efficiently than public enterprises. This definition categorises decentralisation into four types or dimensions: political, fiscal, administrative, and economic decentralisation (Cheema & Rondinelli, 2007). Each type of decentralisation depends on the scope of authority transferred by the central government to local governments and the character and nature of the local governments receiving the authority. A key question in understanding a particular type of decentralisation is assessing the extent of central government control and local autonomy (Braathen & Hellevik, 2008). Therefore, distinguishing the different types and forms will clarify the definition of decentralisation (White, 2011). 1.8.1 Types of Decentralisation There are four types: political, fiscal, administrative and economic or market decentralisation. 1.8.1.2 Political Decentralisation It is a system of government that aims to give more authority to citizens and their elected representatives in decision making and public administration. This concept is usually associated with pluralistic democracy and representative governance. Political decentralisation has also tended to support democratisation by providing more opportunities for citizens and their elected representatives to affect the creation and implementation of policies. Political decentralisation, in this sense, implies that the selection of representatives from local electoral jurisdiction allows citizens to better know their political representatives and allows elected officials to better know the needs and desires of their constituents. However, political decentralisation also requires constitutional or statutory reforms, development of pluralistic political parties, strengthening of legislatures, creation of local political units, and encouragement of effective public interest groups (Rondinelli, 1999: 2). 33 According to Brancati (2006), political decentralisation is associated with power-sharing arrangements among different levels of government, with each level having the power to legislate on at least one subject matter. Manor (2011) defines political or democratic decentralisation as the devolution of powers and resources from higher levels in political systems to elected bodies at lower levels. According to the author, if political decentralisation is to work well, three essential things must be present, namely, (1) substantial powers must be devolved unto elected bodies at lower levels; (2) substantial resources must be devolved unto elected bodies; (3) two types of accountability must be established: first, horizontal accountability of bureaucrats to elected representatives and downward accountability of elected representatives to their constituents. To the author, “If any of these three essentials is absent, the system will fail, if any is present but weak, the system will work less than well. We know of no exception to this set of principles” (Manor, 2011: 3). 1.8.1.3 Fiscal Decentralisation It is commonly defined as the “transfer of fiscal power and resources from the central government to subordinate or quasi-independent (subnational) government units” (Boex, 2009: 2). According to Bahl (2008: 3), fiscal decentralisation is “the process of transferring budgetary authority from the central government to elected subnational governments to grant them the power to make decisions regarding taxes and expenses''. Siegle and O’Mahony (2006) define fiscal decentralisation as the transfer of financial authority to the local level. It involves reducing conditions on the intergovernmental transfer of resources and giving local jurisdictions greater authority to generate revenue. 34 According to (Rondinelli, 1999), if local governments and private organisations are to carry out decentralised functions effectively, they must have adequate revenues transferred from the central government to local governments and the authority to make expenditure decisions. Therefore, under fiscal decentralisation, local government taxing and expenditure autonomy are critical in meeting the needs of the people. 1.8.1.4 Administrative Decentralisation It refers to the transfer of responsibility for planning, financing, and managing certain public functions from the central government to subordinate units or levels of government, semi-autonomous public authorities or corporations, or area-wide, regional, or functional authorities. It seeks to redistribute authority, responsibility and financial resources for providing public services between levels of government (Rondinelli, 1999: 2). Administrative decentralisation focuses on the degree of autonomy local governments enjoy and the extent of central government control over local government. The following issues can measure this level of authority: first, the degree of decision-making authority enjoyed by the local governments; second, the authority to hire and fire their staff and third, the power to make taxing and spending decisions or the authority to control public finances (Schneider, 2003). The literature classifies administrative decentralisation using deconcentration, delegation and devolution. The degree of autonomy each category enjoys differs. According to Schneider (2003), deconcentration involves the least degree of autonomy, delegation slightly more, and devolution the most autonomy. Another difference between these forms of administrative decentralisation is the relationship between the central and local governments. 35 Deconcentration involves a bureaucratic or hierarchical relationship; delegation involves a contractual relationship, and devolution involves an arm’s length relationship (Schneider, 2003). 1.8.1.5 Economic or Market Decentralisation Economic or Market Decentralisation shifts responsibility for functions from the public to the private sector. Market decentralisation allows functions that used to be done exclusively by the government to be performed by businesses, community groups, cooperatives, private voluntary associations, and other nongovernmental organisations. Privatisation and deregulation are the two forms of market decentralisation. Rondinelli, McCullough and Johnson (1989:72) claim that through privatisation and deregulation, some governments have divested themselves of responsibilities for functions either by transferring them to voluntary organisations or by allowing them to be performed by private businesses. In some cases, governments have transferred responsibilities to parallel organisations such as national industrial and trade associations, professional groups, religious organisations, political parties, or cooperatives. These parallel organisations have been given the responsibility to licence, regulate or supervise their members in performing functions that were previously performed or regulated by the government. Under market decentralisation, voluntary organisations can be crucial in expanding access to services. They can be essential in delivering services to meet basic human needs. For example, private organisations can run daycare centres, nursery schools, health clinics, and homes for destitute children and provide vocational training, non-formal education, sports, and recreation programs (Rondinelli, Nellis & Cheema, 1983). 36 Local governments can also privatise by contracting out some government administrative functions. For example, local governments can use private contractors to collect local taxes. Also, local governments can use private consulting firms to fill technical positions such as engineers and accountants since local government pay levels are often too low. These authors also claim that voluntary and religious organisations have been heavily involved in providing primary health care services in rural areas, where government health care programs are inadequate and private health care services are unavailable. 1.8.2 Forms of Decentralisation In addition to the four types of decentralisation, there are also three forms of administrative decentralisation. With all the complexity and mixtures, it is essential to define these three forms of administrative decentralisation: deconcentration, delegation and devolution. 1.8.2.1 Deconcentration Deconcentration is defined as handing over some amount of administrative authority or responsibility to lower levels within central government ministries and agencies. It is a shifting of the workload from centrally located officials to staff or offices outside of the national capital. Deconcentration, when it is more than reorganisation, gives some discretion to field agents to plan and implement programs and projects or to adjust central directives to local conditions, within guidelines set by the central ministry or agency headquarters (Rondinelli, Nellis & Cheema, 1983:15). 37 According to the authors, deconcentration has been the most frequently used form of decentralisation in developing countries since the early 1970s. The distinguishing characteristic of deconcentration has been that the authority for transferring specific functions from the central government to local governments remains within the central government structure. Cheema and Rondinelli (2007:3) define deconcentration as the “shifting of administrative responsibilities from central ministries and departments to regional and local administrative levels by establishing field offices of national departments and transferring some authority for decision-making to regional field staff”. Schneider (2003) states that under deconcentration, the central government retains authority over the field office and exercises that authority through the hierarchical channel of the central government bureaucracy. Secondly, the transfer of responsibilities changes the spatial and geographical distribution of authority but does not significantly change the autonomy of the entity that receives the authority. Finally, deconcentration allows only moderately more authority than centralised systems. According to Ozmen (2014), deconcentration is the weakest form of decentralisation used in unitary states. 1.8.2.2 Delegation Delegation refers to the transfer of managerial responsibility for specifically defined functions to organisations that are outside the regular bureaucratic structure and that are only indirectly controlled by the central government. Delegation has long been used in administrative law. It implies that a sovereign authority creates or transfers to an agent specified functions and duties, which the agent has broad discretion to carry out. However, ultimate responsibility remains with the sovereign authority. In developing countries, responsibilities have been delegated to public corporations, regional development agencies, special function authorities, semi-autonomous implementation units, and a variety of parastatal organisations (Rondinelli, Nellis & Cheema, 1983:19). 38 In delegation, “national governments shift management authority for specific functions to semiautonomous or parastatal organisations and state enterprises, regional planning and area development agencies, and multi-and single purpose public authorities” (Cheema & Rondinelli, 2007: 3). According to Schneider (2003), delegation transfers policy responsibility to local governments or semi-autonomous organisations that are not controlled by the central government but remain accountable to it. The main difference between deconcentration and delegation is that the central government exercises its control through a contractual relationship that enforces the accountability of local governments. Therefore, delegation represents a slightly higher level of administrative autonomy for local entities than deconcentration. That is, delegation is a more extensive form of decentralisation. 1.8.2.3 Devolution Devolution is defined as the creation or strengthening-financially or legally-of subnational national units of government, the activities of which are substantially outside the direct control of the central government. Under devolution, local units of government are autonomous or independent and their legal status makes them separate or distinct from the central government. Central authorities frequently exercise only indirect, supervisory control over such units. Normally, local governments have clear and legally recognised geographical boundaries within which they exercise an exclusive authority to perform explicitly granted or reserved functions. They have corporate or statutory authority to raise revenue and make expenditures. They should be perceived by local citizens as organisations providing services that satisfy their needs, and as governmental units over which they have some influence. Devolution establishes reciprocal and mutually benefitting relationships between central and local governments. That is, the local governments are not merely subordinate administrative units, but they have the ability to interact reciprocally with other units of government in the political system of which they are a part (Rondinelli, Nellis & Cheema, 1983: 25). 39 Under devolution, the central government allows local government units to exercise power and control over the transferred policy. Devolution grants local units the greatest degree of autonomy than deconcentration and delegation. Local governments are only accountable to the central government as much as the central government can impose its will by threatening to withhold resources (Schneider, 2003). According to Cheema and Rondinelli (2007), devolution strengthens local governments by granting them the authority, responsibility, and resources to provide services and formulate and implement local policies. Devolution requires that local governments be given autonomy and be perceived as a different level of government over which the central authorities exercise little or no direct control (Rondinelli, McCullough & Johnson, 1989). 1.8.3 Autonomy Another important concept in the decentralisation literature that warrants our understanding is autonomy. According to Zaharia and Bilouseac (2009), autonomy is the ability of local governments to make independent decisions within the law to solve the problems of their people with limited intervention from the central government. Local autonomy does not mean complete independence or separation from the central government. Instead, the principle of local autonomy provides local authorities with sufficient authority and freedom to manage local public affairs to meet their constituent’s needs. Libonati (2001) holds the view that autonomy refers to the degree of discretionary authority delegated to local governments to determine their form of government and internal organisation: the functions they perform, the power to raise money, borrow and spend, and the power to fix employment conditions of their staff. In addition, autonomy 40 may refer to the local government’s authority to initiate policy and enjoy immunity from the central government. According to Selee (2006), autonomy refers to the degree of powers: administrative, legislative, and judicial powers transferred to local authorities to provide certain essential functions such as building and maintaining roads and streets, providing drinking water and electricity, and obtaining resources to carry out their tasks. Lijphart (2004) suggests that autonomy means that minority groups have the authority to manage their internal affairs, especially in education and culture. To sum up, autonomy is the ability of local governments to manage and control their internal affairs with limited interference from the central government. 1.8.4 Conclusion This chapter discussed the study's introduction, background, and problem statement. The chapter also discussed the purpose statement, the research questions, and the study’s scope and significance. The chapter concluded by defining the key terms used in the study. The next chapter deals with the literature review and the theoretical frameworks. 41 CHAPTER TWO LITERATURE REVIEW Assessing decentralisation as an effective strategy for conflict mitigation. 2.1. Introduction Decentralisation is increasingly being used as an effective strategy to mitigate ethnic conflicts and secessionism. However, decentralisation has been more successful in some countries than others (Brancati, 2006; Bakke, 2008). Therefore, assessing the effectiveness of decentralisation in mitigating conflicts in diverse societies has become increasingly relevant (Tranchant, 2007; Keller, 2007; Burgess, 2011). Decentralisation is defined as the transfer of responsibility for planning, management, and the raising and allocation of resources from the central government and its agencies to field units of government agencies, subordinate units or levels of government, semi-autonomous public authorities or corporations, area-wide, regional or functional authorities, or non-governmental private or voluntary organisations (Rondinelli, Nellis & Cheema, 1983:13). This definition is appropriate for this study because it emphasises intergovernmental relations and an external relationship between the central government and outside organisations. This definition is significant because governance is no longer viewed as the exclusive domain of the central government. Through decentralisation, citizens, civil society organisations and the private sector can also shape public policy (Cheema & Rondinelli, 2007). The objective is that the government, working with 42 citizens and outside organisations, will become more efficient in meeting the needs of the people, thus preventing intrastate conflicts (Cheema & Rondinelli, 2007; Rondinelli, Nellis & Cheema, 1983). However, there is a lack of consensus among scholars regarding the effectiveness of decentralisation in mitigating intrastate conflict. On the one hand, some scholars (Brancati, 2006; Diprose & Ukiwo, 2008; Bakke, 2008; Braathen & Hellevik, 2008; Siegle & O’Mahony, 2006) argue that decentralisation has the potential to either reduce or exacerbate conflicts depending on certain circumstances. On the other hand, other academics (Sambanis & Milanovic, 2009; Beland & Lecours, 2005; 2007; Goodfellow & Lindemann, 2013; Mbuagbo & Fru, 2011; Tambulasi, 2009) contend that decentralisation increases conflicts. However, other scholars (Lake & Rothchild, 1996; Bardhan, 2002; Tranchant, 2007; Burgess, 2011; Grasa & Camps, 2009) even maintain that decentralisation reduces conflicts. The following review of the literature on decentralisation and conflicts confirms the ongoing debate, discusses the conflicting themes and concludes that despite the increasing use of decentralisation to resolve intrastate conflict, the debate remains inconclusive, thus giving room for further research. 2.2 Decentralisation can either reduce or increase conflicts. Although decentralisation is praised as an effective mechanism for conflict mitigation, decentralisation is more successful in reducing conflicts in some countries than in others due to particular circumstances. For example, Brancati (2006), based on a large-N statistical analysis of election results of regional parties in thirty democracies from 1985 to 2000, found that decentralisation has the potential “to decrease ethnic 43 conflicts and secessionism in democracies by bringing the governments closer to the people, increasing their opportunities to participate in government, and giving groups control over their political, social and economic affairs.” Brancati's logic is that by empowering groups to pass legislation to protect their interests and concerns, decentralisation will prevent ethnic groups from fighting each other and reduce the incentive for regions to secede. However, decentralisation may indirectly increase ethnic conflicts and secessionism by encouraging the growth of regional parties, which can increase ethnic conflict and secessionism by reinforcing ethnic and regional identities, passing legislation favouring particular groups over others, and mobilising groups to engage in ethnic conflicts and secessionism. In the article, Brancati explains that the strength of regional parties is the key to understanding why political decentralisation is more successful in reducing ethnic conflict and secessionism in some democracies than in others. Lublin (2012) in analysing the impact of decentralisation on ethno-regional party success using a multipronged approach, namely, a historical analysis, quantitative case studies of Italy and Spain, and a multivariate model of ethno-regional party success in 71 democracies from 1990 through 2011 argues that decentralisation does not consistently strengthen ethno-regional parties. In the article, Lublin demonstrates that ethno-regional parties derive no benefit from decentralisation in non-ethnically decentralised countries but notes that certain types of decentralised institutions may promote ethno-regional party success in ethnically decentralised countries. The author concludes that the impact of decentralisation on ethno-regional parties could be minimised or regulated by granting ethnic and regional minorities autonomy but not statewide influence. Miodownick and 44 Cartrite (2009), using an agent-based model to understand the effectiveness of political decentralisation on ethnopolitical mobilisation, found that weak and medium levels of decentralisation increase the potential for ethnopolitical mobilisation while a strong level of decentralisation dampens regional conflicts. In the article, the authors explain that entrusting regional elites with more responsibilities, under most circumstances, seems to be the most reasonable way to mitigate regional demands for autonomy. According to Schou and Haug (2005), studies on how decentralisation is used to manage conflicts in unitary states are lacking in the literature; therefore, empowering minority groups and ethnic or regional groups with the power and resources to protect their interest could help close the gap in the literature. However, other scholars, who have studied the effects of decentralisation and regional parties on ethnic conflicts and secessionism, suggest that political decentralisation does not reduce ethnic conflict and secessionism; rather, it exacerbates it by reinforcing and strengthening ethnic and regional identities, and by recognising certain ethnic groups and legitimating them over others (Hardgrave, 1994; Kymlicka, 1998) or by empowering groups to make laws that discriminate against other ethnic or religious groups (Harowitz, 1991; Suberu, 1994), and by providing ethnic or regional groups with the resources such as a regional police force, legislature or media to engage in ethnic conflicts and secessionism (Roeder, 1991; Kymlicka, 1998; Bunce, 1999; Snyder, 2000; Cornell, 2002; Eaton, 2006). When the central government is weak, empowered regional governments can escalate their demands for secession. Several authors (Treisman, 1997; Hale, 2000; Bunce, 1999) suggest that a high degree of regional autonomy led to separatist movements in Russia in the 1990s. Bunce (1999) argues that the federal 45 structures of the Soviet Union, Yugoslavia and Czechoslovakia contributed to their collapse because they encouraged a shift in power from the centre to the regions, providing resources to regional actors for mobilisation. The creation of new districts and the unequal distribution of power can dampen or intensify intrastate conflicts. In Uganda, where President Yoweri Museveni implemented decentralisation in 1986, Green (2008) found that decentralisation reduced national-level conflicts but increased local-level conflicts. In the article, Green explains that the decentralisation program was designed to transfer equal power to all five levels of local governments. However, in practice, power was concentrated only at the district level. The concentration of power and resources at the district level led to conflicts over district-level leadership positions. Likewise, Siegle and O’Mahony (2006) found that decentralisation has a differentiated effect on ethnic conflict. From their statistical analysis, the authors demonstrate that decentralisation programs that support elected leaders, higher local government expenditures, and employment opportunities are less likely to have ethnic conflicts. However, decentralisation measures in countries with higher local government taxes were more likely to experience ethnic conflicts. Implementing decentralisation in countries with historical grievances and income inequalities among minority groups has produced mixed results. In a comparative case study in some towns in Nigeria and Indonesia where inter-group relations resulted in violent conflicts, Diprose and Ukiwo (2008) found that decentralisation mitigated conflicts by accommodating ethnic diversity and managing historical grievances by meeting the needs of the people. However, decentralisation resulted in violent conflicts with strong perceptions of unequal access to power and resources between ethnic and 46 religious groups. In explaining how economic factors shape demands for greater autonomy, Sambanis and Milanovic (2009) claim that more prominent, prosperous and resource-rich regions are more likely to demand sovereignty or policy autonomy than poorer regions. The authors also stated that ethnically distinct regions with low levels of autonomy would be more likely to engage in conflicts with their governments. Decentralisation plays an ambiguous role in peacemaking and conflict management. Braathen and Hellevik's (2008) research on the role of decentralisation in peacemaking and conflict management processes claims that in some cases, decentralisation as a power-sharing arrangement could provide opportunities for peace and conflict management, while in other cases, power-sharing could trigger further conflict. From their review of several armed conflicts in Africa, the authors conclude that decentralisation leads to lasting peace when there is an interdependent relationship between the central and local governments. As the authors explain, such a relationship requires the central government to devolve powers and resources to local governments, maintain fiscal equity between local governments and ensure local governments are accountable. Similarly, Bakke (2008), based on a study on how decentralisation can be peace-preserving, claims that decentralisation can be peace-preserving or exacerbate conflicts depending on the ethnic composition and wealth of a region. In exploring the conditions under which decentralisation could be peace-preserving, the author examined three case studies in which central governments had conflicts with subnational governments. These three conflictual centre-region relations included Moscow’s relationship with Chechnya, India's relationship with Punjab and Quebec’s relationship 47 with Canada. Using a combination of secondary and primary sources and interviews, the author found that decentralisation can reduce or increase ethnic conflicts depending on the ethnic composition and levels of wealth in a region. For example, decentralisation could mitigate conflicts if regions were granted fiscal and policy autonomy over issues such as language and religion important to minority groups’ recognition, protection, and safety. However, resource-rich regions with low levels of fiscal decentralisation will fight for more financial autonomy. Bakke also found that ethnic groups that perceive the state as a threat to their survival or autonomy will also intensify ethnic mobilisation for autonomy. Marinzel (2014) suggests that wealthy regions or groups in an unequal society may want to succeed because they find it burdensome to subsidise the rest of the nation. For example, Catalonia, one of Spain's richest and most highly industrialised regions, wants to secede because they claim they are paying more taxes to the central government than they are spending on social programs or infrastructure. 2.3. Decentralisation has the potential to reduce conflicts. In the past decades, decentralisation has become one of the most prominent tools for mitigating intrastate conflicts around the world (Bakke, 2008; Sambanis & Milanovic, 2009; Keil & Anderson, 2018). In response to the rise of these types of conflicts, scholars and policymakers have developed institutional strategies such as regional autonomy or regional self-government, accommodation of ethnic diversity and power-sharing arrangements to resolve ethnic conflicts and secessionism. Decentralisation has been viewed as an effective conflict mitigation strategy granting ethnic or regional groups autonomy to control their local affairs. For example, Bakke (2008) claims that 48 decentralisation granted Northern Ireland a legislative assembly within the United Kingdom during the Good Friday Agreement of 1998, ending 30 years old religious conflict between the Protestants and the Catholics. Bakke added that in 2005, decentralisation also mitigated another 30-year-old conflict between the Indonesian government and the separatist Islamist Free Aceh rebels. The rebels agreed to give up their armed struggle in exchange for the right to establish regional self-government. According to Tranchant (2016), the relative success of decentralisation in countries like Switzerland, Canada and Belgium has given credence to autonomy as a conflict resolution strategy. The institutional design of autonomy has been used to mitigate conflicts by protecting the identity and interest of marginalised minorities from central government intrusion and domination (Lake & Rothchild, 1996; Rothchild & Hartzell, 1999). Lake and Rothchild (1996) found that decentralisation plays a role in mitigating political conflicts by enabling local and regional authorities to have some degree of autonomous power within a larger state. In discussing the origins and management of ethnic conflicts, the authors claim that ethnic conflicts are not caused directly by inter-group differences, ancient hatreds or centuries-old feuds. Instead, ethnic conflicts are often caused when minority groups fear for their security and safety. In the paper, Lake and Rothchild highlight that politically marginalised groups who continue to fear majority domination and have experienced excessive state intrusion into their local affairs prefer autonomy because it places institutional limitations on the central government’s authority. The authors conclude that marginalised groups view autonomy as a check and balance 49 mechanism to insulate their interests from the overreaching power of the central government. Likewise, Rothchild & Hartzell (1999) claim that autonomy or self-government could also reassure minorities, who would otherwise worry that central governments can interfere with their local affairs. According to the authors, decentralisation enables groups to have control of their local affairs and provides important checks on the central government. By having a regional legislature with policy-making powers, minority groups can limit the central government's excessive intervention in their local affairs. Bakke and Wibbles (2006) suggest that “minority groups, fearful of being assimilated, integrated or worse still eliminated, having decentralised institutions helps improve their sense of stability, security and confidence in the state.” Lublin (2012) suggests that decentration safeguards regions from central government power, protects their language and culture, and shapes regional economic development. According to Bardhan (2002), decentralisation is a strategy for diffusing social and political tensions and ensuring local cultural and political autonomy. Autonomy enables ethnic or regional groups to legislate in some areas important to them, thus dampening their secessionist ambitions. For instance, Brancati (2006) claims that decentralisation reduces intrastate conflicts by granting autonomy to regions through regional legislatures. In the paper, Brancati explains that political decentralisation is a system of government in which there is a vertical division of power among multiple tiers of government that have independent decision-making power at least over one subject matter. The author concludes that decentralisation “reduces ethnic conflict and secession in democracies by bringing the government closer to the people, 50 increasing opportunities to participate in government, and giving groups control of their political, social and economic affairs.” By enabling regions or ethnic groups to make laws to protect their interest and concerns, decentralisation prevents ethnic groups from fighting each other or trying to secede. McGarry and O’Leary (1993) also note that in a truly decentralised system, minorities are given constitutional powers to “legislate on important areas, such as language, religion and education, while leaving other policy briefs-defence and fiscal policies-to the central government.” In this sense, decentralisation is a conflict mitigation strategy because it provides embattled minority groups with legitimate channels to articulate their grievances, regulate important policy issues and protect their status. Likewise, Tranchant (2007), using decentralisation as an empowerment model, found that decentralisation can reduce ethnic conflict by empowering minority groups to control their local affairs. In the article, the author demonstrates that the empowerment of minority groups is easily reached if they are geographically concentrated in one region representing the majority or a significant minority of the population. The author explains that decentralisation will reduce ethnic conflicts by devolving power to minority groups to design and implement public policies according to their preferences. In another study, Tranchant (2016) found that regional autonomy is an effective tool for curbing conflict between local majority groups within a given population. Autonomy arrangements have also been used as a compromise solution to mitigate violent self-determination struggles between ethnic minority rebels and national governments. Fujikawa (2021), based on the case study of Aceh in Indonesia, found that autonomy was used as a compromise solution between Aceh rebels who were fighting for 51 independence and the government of Indonesia that was unwilling to relinquish their sovereignty. In the article, Fujikawa pointed out that warring parties in ethnonational conflicts tend to be reluctant to resolve their conflicts for two reasons. First, national governments have no incentive to offer substantial concessions to ethnic minority rebels because rebels in ethnonational conflicts tend to be poorly armed and incapable of inflicting severe damage on the government. Second, rebels have difficulty believing national governments will be committed to any signed agreement in the long run. However, the national government of Indonesia accepted an autonomy arrangement with the Free Aceh Movement rebels because of the cumulative cost of the protracted conflict, and the rebels signed the agreement because of the backing of the international community. The agreement stated that Indonesia would remain a unitary state but would guarantee a certain degree of self-rule to the Aceh region. In this sense, autonomy is a compromise strategy between ethnic groups seeking self-determination and national governments protecting their sovereignty (Caspersen, 2017). Likewise, research by Keil and Anderson (2018) highlights that autonomy arrangements can act as a compromise between warring parties by granting minority groups sufficient autonomy to control their economic, political and social affairs while preserving the state. Additionally, autonomy arrangements have also been used to prevent secessionist movements. According to Keil and Anderson (2018), separatist movements are found worldwide, and states have used decentralisation to derail their plans for independence. In the article, Keith and Anderson suggest that for some minorities, having a devolved parliament with law-making powers over a limited subject matter will be enough incentive to give up their ambition to secede. Similarly, Lustick et al. (2004) 52 suggest that granting autonomy to disgruntled minorities can prevent secession while preserving the stability of the central state. Using decentralisation to accommodate ethnic diversity has been praised as a conflict mitigation strategy in diverse societies. Yusoff, Sarjoon and Hassan (2016), through the review of literature on decentralisation as a tool for ethnic diversity accommodation, found that decentralisation has been used to accommodate diverse ethnic groups in a larger political system where socio-cultural, economic and political differences exist. The findings indicate that granting minority groups greater control over their local affairs assures them that the government recognises their interests and concerns. The authors conclude that by giving minorities a voice in the government, decentralisation is viewed as a flexible strategy for accommodating the concerns and priorities of diverse ethnic groups within a larger population. Miodownick and Cartrite (2009:14) suggest that “policymakers may find that accommodation, rather than suppression or control, of the diverse interests of regions and groups” will mitigate intrastate conflicts while also protecting the integrity of the state. Lustick et al. (2004) suggest that although repression may work to suppress ethnopolitical movements in the short term, it does not effectively reduce the threat of secession. Decentralisation as a power-sharing arrangement is often cited as a solution for mitigating ethnic conflicts and consolidating democracy in diverse societies. Lijphart (2004) states that power-sharing involves the participation of representatives of all significant communal groups in political decision-making, especially at the executive level. Norris (2008), in his seminal work on power-sharing institutions, found that power-sharing arrangements avoid winner-take-all elections and guarantee minorities a 53 voice in the government. With the assurance that they will not be dominated or excluded from the government, ethnic minorities are less likely to take actions that will undermine the territorial stability of the state. As explained by Norris, power-sharing arrangements encourage diverse societies to be more inclusive and tolerant of other groups because it deemphasises ethnic identities. Similarly, Burgess (2011), based on a study of power-sharing institutions in 48 Sub-Saharan African countries, found that decentralisation could help mitigate conflicts by including people from different minority groups in decision-making. Burgess found a strong and significant correlation between power-sharing institutions and democracy and stability in Sub-Saharan Africa. The author explains that decentralisation is an essential strategy for defending the interest and protecting the rights of spatially concentrated groups. Similarly, Grasa and Camps (2009), in a study to understand the linkage between decentralised governance and conflict prevention, found that decentralisation reduces conflicts by including minorities in decision-making. Likewise, Siegle and O’Mahony (2006) suggest that the conflict-mitigation rationale for decentralisation in ethnically divided societies offers minority groups opportunities for participation and representation in government. A study by Lustick et al. (2004) indicates that representative types of power-sharing are more effective than repression of ethnopolitical movements in reducing the threat of secession. The authors argue that if governments respond positively to the demands of disgruntled minorities, secession could be prevented while preserving the state’s territorial integrity. As the authors explain, power-sharing arrangements will encourage secessionist groups to feel confident in representing and protecting their interests and concerns, thus mitigating their demands for secession. However, Durante 54 (2017) suggests that regional autonomy alone might not reduce conflicts; instead, regional autonomy for a territorially concentrated ethnic group and governmental power-sharing with minority groups within the central executive is necessary for decentralisation to reduce ethnic conflict and secessionism. Studies using decentralisation as a conflict mitigation strategy in pluralistic societies that have become unitary states are not common in the literature; therefore, these studies taking as a whole, which have used different institutional strategies such as autonomy to protect the identity and interest of marginalised minorities from central government intrusion and domination (Lake & Rothchild, 1996; Rothchild & Hartzell, 1999), accommodating ethnic diversities to include minorities in government (Yusoff, Sarjoon and Hassan, 2016) and using power-sharing arrangements which encourage diverse societies to be more inclusive and tolerant of other groups (Norris, 2008) could help close the gap. 2.4. Decentralisation can exacerbate conflicts Although decentralisation is perceived as an effective mechanism for resolving intrastate conflicts, other scholars have adopted a more pessimistic view. For example, Snyder (2000: 327), discussing the violent dissolution of former Yugoslavia in the early 1990s, stated that granting autonomy concessions has a “terrible track record” in resolving intrastate conflicts. Decentralisation can lead to ever-growing demands for greater autonomy or secession by empowering regional leaders who engage in ethnic conflicts, empowering groups to legislate discriminatory laws against other minorities and reinforcing ethnic or regional differences among groups. For example, research by 55 Colomb et al. (2014) suggests that decentralisation has led subnational movements with strong regional identities in Scotland in the United Kingdom, Catalonia in Spain, and Flanders in Belgium to intensify their demands for more autonomy or territorial independence. In the same way, Beland and Lecours (2005, 2007) claim that the implementation of social policies in Canada, the United Kingdom, and Belgium have also inspired regional leaders to demand greater autonomy for their regions. Some scholars (Bunce, 1999; Synder, 2000; Riker, 1964) claim that decentralisation encourages ethnic conflicts and secessionism by providing regions with resources like regional legislatures and police that make it easier for groups to engage in ethnic or regional conflicts. Eaton (2006) claims that decentralisation, instituted to resolve the armed conflict that plagued Columbia for decades, allowed regional parties to win elections and mobilise resources to engage in regional conflicts. According to Keith and Anderson (2018), in trying to accommodate and protect ethnic and cultural identities, decentralisation may reinforce the very identities and cultural traits which minority groups claim make them different. Legislation which promotes the language and cultural characteristics of minority groups could deepen ethnic identities and ensure the continuation of ethnic differences. The authors explain that ethnic differences could erode any unity between minority groups, cement diverse identities, and promote differences among groups, thus contributing to political tension. Decentralisation could increase conflicts when the central government undermines the authority of elected officials. For instance, Mbuagbo and Fru (2011), based on the study of the 2004 Law implementing decentralisation in Cameroon, found that the overreaching influence of government officials over regional and local authorities 56 undermined the authority of elected mayors and councillors, thus resulting in conflicts. The author also found that the decentralisation law needed to define the roles of appointed and elected officials clearly. The powers devolved by the state to local authorities were not exclusive. They were exercised concurrently by the central government and the local authorities. Therefore, conflicts occurred because each side interpreted the law in their favour. In another paper by Mbuagbo (2012) on urban governance policies in Cameroon, the author found a similar result of decentralisation intensifying conflicts between government representatives and elected mayors because of competing interpretations of the law. Similarly, in a study on the relationship between decentralisation and institutional conflicts at the local government level in Malawi from 2000 to 2005, Tambulasi (2009) found that poorly designed decentralisation increased institutional conflicts at the local government level. By reviewing primary and secondary data on decentralisation from government publications and newspapers and conducting interviews with government and elected officials, the author found that decentralisation did not transfer real power to local governments. Therefore, local government officials felt powerless in the exercise of their duties. As a result, conflicts occurred when they tried to assert their authority against central government intrusion. Tambulasi also pointed out that because the roles and powers of the councillors and parliamentarians were not clearly defined, power struggles occurred between the councillors and parliamentarians. Decentralisation intensifies conflicts when the government refuses to share political power and resources with ethnic or regional groups. In exploring and assessing Ethiopia’s democratisation and decentralisation experiment, Merera (2007:82) found that the “top-down approach of the ruling party” to maintain control over the Oromo people 57 instead of sharing political power and resources with the regional group exacerbates conflicts. The author conducted a case study of the Oromo people, the country’s largest ethnic group. In the article, the author explains that the Oromo and the Southern Ethiopian People’s regions produced coffee which constituted more than 60% of the country’s foreign exchange earnings but was allotted a disproportionate share from the national treasury. Through interviews, focus group discussions, and official reports and publications, the author found that the central government was reluctant to evenly distribute national resources and share political power with the region, thus generating intrastate conflicts between the Oromo people and the central government. The Oromo people have been fighting for self-rule since the 1960s because of the marginalisation of their region. Erk (2014) claims decentralisation in Africa, specifically in South Africa, Ethiopia and Nigeria, has politicised local conflicts and increased competition and disputes between ethnic groups over land, water and natural resources. Schou and Haug (2005) suggest that inequalities in the distribution of state resources for development projects can stir up envy between different regions, thus leading to ethnic conflicts in already polarised societies. Gurr (2000) suggests that ethnic minorities with no access to power tend to intensify their demand for independence from the central government. Durante (2017) claims that the government's mistreatment of minorities triggers ethnic conflicts. Premdas (2000) suggests that when ethno-regional and ethnonational groups are frustrated in their quest for recognition and resources, they usually fight against the central state. According to Woodward (2007), “economic deprivation, political neglect, and forced cultural assimilation have in recent years resulted in minority nations taking up arms to fight for the protection of their identity and 58 their independence from the host state.” Decentralisation increases conflicts when there is a history of government discrimination and repression against ethnic minorities (Sambanis & Milanovic, 2009). Decentralisation will likely increase intrastate conflicts when the central government erodes the autonomy of ethnic or regional groups that previously enjoyed freedom. Research by Goodfellow and Lindemann (2013) on the relationship between the national government and traditional institutions in Uganda suggests that decentralisation increased violence between the Buganda Kingdom and the central government because the central government infringed on the autonomy of the Buganda Kingdom. The introduction of decentralisation by President Museveni in the 1980s eroded the autonomy of the Buganda kingdom, which had enjoyed autonomy before joining Uganda’s independence in 1962, by transferring part of the management of Buganda’s land from their king’s control to the central government. To the Buganda elites, the loss of their land meant a weakening of their kingdom’s influence. While the Buganda kingdom wanted to preserve their autonomy and control their entire land, the central government wanted to weaken the kingdom’s autonomy and institute a national land management program. Therefore, the clash of institutional interests between the Buganda Kingdom and the central government resulted in violent conflicts in 2009. The authors concluded that the refusal of the central government to allow the Buganda Kingdom to maintain their autonomy and control its land motivated the Buganda elites to continue their fight for self-rule. Manyak and Katono (2010) suggest that decentralisation increased conflicts in local governments in Uganda because President Museveni wanted to maintain political control over local governments. Similarly, Marinzel (2014) claims that the secessionist 59 desire within Catalonia stems from a history of the Spanish government eroding its regional autonomy. In the article, the author suggests that after General Francisco Franco came to power in Spain, his goal was to unite Spain and rid it of anything that encouraged disunity. Therefore, Catalonia’s autonomy was revoked, its language was outlawed, and Catalan intellectuals were persecuted. The author concludes that the long history of persecution continues to inspire Catalonians to fight for independence. Seigle and O’Mahony (2006) claim that studies using context in analysing conflicts are lacking in the literature as two-thirds of intrastate conflicts have occurred in autocratic political environments; therefore, these studies which have examined the history of political persecution, oppression and discrimination against minority groups could help narrow the gap in the literature. 2.5. Conclusion Intrastate conflicts remain a major problem in international politics today. To prevent this type of conflict worldwide, governments have turned to decentralisation as one of the tools to mitigate intrastate conflicts ( Bakke, 2008; Sambanis & Milanovic, 2009). Despite the increased use of decentralisation to resolve intrastate conflicts, the debate remains inconclusive (Smoke, 2003; White, 2011; Bakke, 2008). There is still no clear answer to why decentralisation is more successful in reducing conflicts in some countries than others. The literature review identified three conflicting themes held by scholars and practitioners regarding the effectiveness of decentralisation in mitigating conflicts. 60 On the one hand, several scholars have suggested that decentralisation has the potential to either reduce or increase conflicts depending on certain circumstances (Brancati, 2006; Bakke, 2008; Bunce, 1999; Synder, 2000; Suberu, 1994; Siegle & O’Mahony, 2006). On the other hand, some have argued that decentralisation has the potential to mitigate intrastate conflicts (Fujikawa, 2021; Durante, 2017; Burgess, 2011; Grasa & Camps, 2009; Tranchant, 2007, 2016; Yusoff et al., 2016). Others have maintained that decentralisation exacerbates conflicts (Goodfellow & Lindemann, 2013; Mbuagbo & Fru, 2011; Merera, 2007; Tambulasi, 2009; Eaton, 2006). Decentralisation is not a panacea to cure all kinds of intrastate conflicts. The use of decentralisation to mitigate conflicts in the developed and developing world has been widely documented. However, a major limitation of this literature is that numerous studies have focused mainly on the relationship between decentralisation and ethnic or regional conflicts. Therefore, further research is needed to understand the relationship between decentralisation and conflict arising from former independent colonial territories that reunited under a federal system but later evolved into a unitary state, especially when their preferences and interests differ. 2.6. The Theoretical Framework This research is grounded in and supported by the theory of decentralisation. According to Rondinelli, Nellis & Cheema (1983:13), decentralisation is defined as the transfer of responsibility for planning, management, and the raising and allocation of resources from the central government and its agencies to field units of government agencies, subordinate units or levels of government, semi-autonomous public 61 authorities or corporations, area-wide, regional or functional authorities, or non-governmental private or voluntary organisations. This definition is relevant to this study, given its emphasis on intergovernmental fiscal relations and the relationship between the government, the private sector, and civil society organisations. This idea of intergovernmental fiscal relations refers to the distribution of powers and resources among the different levels of government. The main idea is to determine which public functions should be centralised and which should be assigned to subnational governments. Fiscal transfers make the government more efficient in providing public goods and services according to the people’s preferences (Tiebout, 1956; Oates, 1972). This definition does not only view decision-making as the exclusive domain of the government but also as the right of citizens and civil society to shape public policy (Cheema & Rondinelli, 2007; Besley & Smart, 2007; Crook & Manor, 2000). The assumption is that by empowering local governments to design and implement public policies according to the preferences of their people, decentralisation will reduce conflicts (Brancati, 2006; Tranchant, 2007; Hechter, 2000). Historically, the literature on decentralisation and conflict mitigation is derived from the classical theory of fiscal federalism or the first-generation theory of fiscal federalism (FGFF) and the second-generation theory of fiscal federalism (SGFF). According to Porcelli (2009), the classical theory of fiscal federalism could be understood from two main contributors. The first contributor is Tiebout (1956), who developed Tiebout's model of local public good provision. According to Tiebout’s model, local governments compete in offering a mi